登陆注册
15713600000020

第20章

goods units of value The negative element arises from the indifference with which men naturally regard goods. Only when forced to it, do we transfer our interest from the uses of goods to the goods themselves; and, in the process of transferring, we have to overcome a natural opposition which varies in strength according to the circumstances. The greater the need, the more eager will we be to get possession and keep possession of goods: the smaller in this case will be the opposition. The opposition will be completely broken down where our need rises to extremity, for here we identify our destiny with that of the goods, and in their loss we see our own calamity. On the other hand, the opposition will be complete where everything is present in superfluity; here we can enjoy without any feeling of gratitude for, or interest in, the objects which procure for us the enjoyment. Between extremest need and superfluity the opposition is a graduated one: we bestow upon goods an amount of interest derived from the interest we have in the services they render us. But we do not give them the whole of this interest; we make a certain reservation. That is to say, all the single items of a stock are considered only at the value of their marginal utility. The surplus value, that which goes beyond their marginal utility, is withheld from the goods.

Here, then, is the numerical expression for the strength of this opposition: the negative element in the formation of value is equal to the subtracted surplus value. Making use once again of the foregoing figures, we find that, so long as we own only one good, there is no deduction in the formation of its value; the entire value of the use is transferred, undiminished, to the good. With two goods, on the other hand, there will be a deduction of 1 from the value, as each of these is valued only according to its marginal utility 9, while the utilities of both added together amount to 10 + 9. Three goods have each a value only of 8, and their utility is equal to 10 + 9 + 8, the surplus value deducted being therefore 3. Reckoning further in the same way, we shall find the minus amount in the formation of value as follows: --With a stock of the minus is 1 02 1

3 3

4 6

5 10

6 15

7 21

8 28

9 36

10 45

11 55

goods units of value.

If we put together the plus and minus amounts we shall obtain the following as result: --Positive (+) Negative (-)Residual (+)1 10 0102 19 1183 27 3244 34 6285 40 10306 45 15307 49 21288 52 28249 54 361810 55 451011 55 55 0goods units of value units of value units of value Thus we obtain the same scale as that which resulted from the multiplication of amount by marginal utility.

It is now seen that the apparent irregularity of the scale is really a consequence of the strict regularity of its conditions.

The value of a supply must increase with the increase of its items so long as the positive element preponderates; in other words, so long as the increment of value, furnished by the utility of the newly-acquired good, is greater than the value which is lost through the decrement of value which its addition causes to every good already in the stock. This is the ascending branch of the movement of value, or, as we might call it, the "up grade" of value.

On the other hand, the value of a supply must decrease with its augmentation, whenever the negative element gains the ascendency. This is the descending branch of the movement of value, or the "down grade" of value.

Strange though it seems, the value must touch zero twice in the course of its development: in the one case, where we have nothing; in the other, where we have everything. If we possess nothing, there are no objects to value; if we possess everything, there is -- just on account of the superfluity -- no subjective inducement to an act of valuation. Only if we possess something -- be it much or little -- does the phenomenon of value appear;and between the two zero points, so different in their importance, it has its existence. It presents itself with the first goods that come into our possession, and increases up to a certain culminating point, from which it decreases, until, when superfluity is reached, interest is again completely withdrawn from the goods.

As a matter of fact, human economies move almost entirely in the ascending branch. In most things we are so far from having a superfluity that almost every multiplication of goods shows a corresponding increase in the total value. The single good certainly falls in value as the stock increases, but as a rule we find that the loss in the items is outweighed by the gain on the whole. On this account we are accustomed to measure wealth and riches by the sum of value of their constituent parts, and regard it as a misfortune if the value of property and revenue goes down. And therefore it appears to us paradoxical when, at times, we are forced to notice that, although the amount of goods and of enjoyments, of wealth and well-being, has been augmented, their value has decreased. It may be that exceptionally favourable weather has resulted in an over-abundant harvest; or it may be the discovery of some new productive stratum of unsuspected fertility; or some sudden and enormous increase of returns through advance in technical processes: or it may be caused by some error on the part of the producer, who has been misled by greed of gain, or a mistaken and exaggerated estimate of demand, into too greatly enlarging his production. But it is always some unusual accident when individual branches of economy are transferred to the descending branch in the movement of value. It is improbable that our whole economic system will ever permanently come under such favourable conditions, and production be brought so near to superfluity, that the ascending movement of value will cease to be the dominant one. The example, however, of those few free goods which nature offers leaves us no room for doubt that value disappears whenever superfluity is reached; and this is really the best proof for our contention that value must begin to decrease whenever superfluity approaches. Even though experience shows the scale of value to have many gaps, yet it gives us sufficient facts to let us trace its ideal course from end to end.

同类推荐
  • 佛说观普贤菩萨行法经

    佛说观普贤菩萨行法经

    本书为公版书,为不受著作权法限制的作家、艺术家及其它人士发布的作品,供广大读者阅读交流。
  • 艺苑雌黄

    艺苑雌黄

    本书为公版书,为不受著作权法限制的作家、艺术家及其它人士发布的作品,供广大读者阅读交流。
  • The Cash Boy

    The Cash Boy

    本书为公版书,为不受著作权法限制的作家、艺术家及其它人士发布的作品,供广大读者阅读交流。
  • 五苦章句经

    五苦章句经

    本书为公版书,为不受著作权法限制的作家、艺术家及其它人士发布的作品,供广大读者阅读交流。
  • 六根归道论

    六根归道论

    本书为公版书,为不受著作权法限制的作家、艺术家及其它人士发布的作品,供广大读者阅读交流。
热门推荐
  • 黑暗元素

    黑暗元素

    这是一个元气的世界,九大属性统治的时代。阴阳双属性的转变,极致烈阳神炎与极致幽冥神火会碰撞出怎样的火花?光明与黑暗是否就真的是如同传说一般都,正义与邪恶的斗争?大陆的奇异种族又是否能够会与人类和平相处?拥有了帝王至尊之位是否就真的坐拥了一切?实力达到了顶峰是否就真正的无所需求?不要被事物的表面现象所迷惑,所有的疑惑与答案都将在这里,为您一一呈现。带您认识一个全新的世界,见证一颗新星的崛起……
  • 哲理荟萃

    哲理荟萃

    《微型小说·哲理荟萃》精选了近百年来中外著名作家创作的经典哲理微型小说。正如费尔巴哈说:“观察自然,观察人吧!在这里你们可以看到哲理的秘密。”这些名篇佳作在智慧性和艺术性方面都代表了世界的最高成就,具有很强的阅读性和欣赏性,深受广大读者喜爱,拥有广泛而深远的影响。这些作品不仅能使我们感受到名家的聪明才智、思考能力和创作魅力,还为我们提供了一个可供欣赏、学习和研究世界微型小说的范本,非常具有收藏价值。
  • 依依的星星

    依依的星星

    本作品实名为《星星》……额……好像也没什么可以介绍了……
  • 致命溺宠:神医小邪妃

    致命溺宠:神医小邪妃

    古武天才少女,身怀万古至宝异世重生,九洲大陆一朝风云诡变。痴傻大小姐华丽变身,激逆天活血脉,修绝世秘籍,炼上古丹方。为解那弥天身世,踏上疑点重重的寻亲之路,一路各种艳遇,各种上古神兽纷纷前来认主。某俊美无双的腹黑男,一路算计,一路装孱弱博同情,攻其不备,一举扑倒。
  • 曾经的曾经花开无声

    曾经的曾经花开无声

    本文主要是根据我自己的亲身经历而写,它细数了我十八年来所经历的酸甜苦辣,一路走来既有花香四溢也有电闪雷鸣;既有清泉水落山涧的清凉也有大漠孤烟的炙热......曾以为自己是这个世界上最孤独的人,所以特别害怕孤独,长大后才明白,在同一片星空下每个人都是孤独的产物,只有在孤独的孕育中人才能得到真正的成长;曾以为自己是这个世界上最没用的人,长大后才发现,并不是自己没用,而是没有发现自己真正的用处,即使是废品卖也是能够回收利用的;曾以为自己是这个世界上最爱他的人,但几年后回头发现,他的模样已在脑海里模糊不清,唯一能回味到的仅是当时的心情......
  • 冷眼观

    冷眼观

    《冷眼观》是晚清时期颇为著名的谴责小说之一。作者通过描写那奇奇怪怪的现状,给我们描绘了一幅行将崩溃的晚清帝国的图卷。《冷眼观》在写作方面也是颇有成就的。结构比较完整,情节曲折,故事通俗生动。作者文笔老到,与内容相适应,全书呈现一种凄凉悲怆的情调。
  • 异界之御剑修仙

    异界之御剑修仙

    在游戏中有着极品装备的大神级高手,因为一次意外,穿越到异界,从此凭借游戏技能,走向巅峰...
  • 窦文涛的说话之道

    窦文涛的说话之道

    本书以窦文涛的说话技巧为核心,同时结合具体个案,深入浅出地与读者共同探讨锻炼口才、提高表达能力的有效方法。
  • 灭魔纪

    灭魔纪

    今日伤我一言,他日断你万骨。魔之纪元,我主沉浮!
  • 腹黑竹马拐青梅

    腹黑竹马拐青梅

    花开花落,青梅再次成熟,竹马再次破芽,郎骑竹马来,绕床弄青梅。当青梅成熟掉下,不知又会落入谁的腹中?当竹马俊悄挺拔,不知又会为谁遮风挡雨?花开花落,故人重逢,花开花散,好久不见!